“柠檬”的市场质量的不确定性和市场机制【外文翻译】.doc

上传人:文初 文档编号:46707 上传时间:2018-05-18 格式:DOC 页数:16 大小:74KB
下载 相关 举报
“柠檬”的市场质量的不确定性和市场机制【外文翻译】.doc_第1页
第1页 / 共16页
“柠檬”的市场质量的不确定性和市场机制【外文翻译】.doc_第2页
第2页 / 共16页
“柠檬”的市场质量的不确定性和市场机制【外文翻译】.doc_第3页
第3页 / 共16页
“柠檬”的市场质量的不确定性和市场机制【外文翻译】.doc_第4页
第4页 / 共16页
“柠檬”的市场质量的不确定性和市场机制【外文翻译】.doc_第5页
第5页 / 共16页
点击查看更多>>
资源描述

1、 外文翻译 原文 The market for “lemons“: quality uncertainty and the market mechanism Material Source: The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 1970 Author:GEORGE A. AKERLOF I. INTRODUCTION This paper relates quality and uncertainty. The existence of goods of many grades poses interesting and important problems

2、 for the theory of markets. On the one hand, the interaction of quality differences and uncertainty may explain important institutions of the labor market. On the other hand, this paper presents a struggling attempt to give structure to the statement: “Business in underdeveloped countries is difficu

3、lt“; in particular, a structure is given for determining the economic costs of dishonesty. Additional applications of the theory include comments on the structure of money markets, on the notion of “insurability,“ on the liquidity of durables, and on brand-name goods. There are many markets in which

4、 buyers use some market statistic to judge the quality of prospective purchases. In this case there is incentive for sellers to market poor quality merchandise, since the returns for good quality accrue mainly to the entire group whose statistic is affected rather than to the individual seller. As a

5、 result there tends to be a reduction in the average quality of goods and also in the size of the market. It should also be perceived that in these markets social and private returns differ, and therefore, in some cases, governmental intervention may increase the welfare of all parties. Or private i

6、nstitutions may arise to take advantage of the potential increases in welfare which can accrue to all parties. By nature, however, these institutions are non atomistic, and therefore concentrations of power with ill consequences of their own can develop. The automobile market is used as a finger exe

7、rcise to illustrate and develop these thoughts. It should be emphasized that this market is chosen for its concreteness and ease in understanding rather than for its importance or realism. II. THE MODEL WITH AUTOMOBILES AS AN EXAMPLE A.The Automobiles Market The example of used cars captures the ess

8、ence of the problem. From time to time one hears either mention of or surprise at the large price difference between new cars and those which have just left the showroom. The usual lunch table justification for this phenomenon the pure joy of owning a “new“ car. We offer a different explanation. Sup

9、pose (for the sake of clarity rather than reality) that there are just four kinds of cars. There are new cars and used cars. There are good cars and bad cars (which in America are known as “lemons“). A new car may be a good car or a lemon, and of course the same is true of used cars. The individuals

10、 in this market buy a new automobile without knowing whether the car they buy will be good or a lemon. But they do know that with probability q it is a good car and with probability (1-q) it is a lemon; by assumption, q is the proportion of good cars produced and (1-q) is the proportion of lemons. A

11、fter owning a specific car, however, for a length of time, the car owner can form a good idea of the quality of this machine; i.e., the owner assigns a new probability to the event that his car is a lemon. This estimate is more accurate than the original estimate. An asymmetry in available informati

12、on has developed: for the sellers now have more knowledge about the quality of a car than the buyers. But good cars and bad cars must still sell at the same price since it is impossible for a buyer to tell the difference between a good car and a bad car. It is apparent that a used car cannot have th

13、e same valuation as a new car .if it did have the same valuation, it would clearly be advantageous to trade a lemon at the price of new car, and buy another new car, at a higher probability q of being good and a lower probability of being bad. Thus the owner of a good machine must be locked in. Not

14、only is it true that he cannot receive the true value of his car, but he cannot even obtain the expected value of a new car. Greshams law has made a modified reappearance. For most cars traded will be the “lemons,“ and good cars may not be traded at all. The “bad“ cars tend to drive out the good (in

15、 much the same way that bad money drives out the good). But the analogy with Greshams law is not quite complete: bad cars drive out the good because they sell at the same price as good cars; similarly, bad money drives out good because the exchange rate is even. But the bad cars sell at the same pri

16、ce as good cars since it is impossible for a buyer to tell the difference between a good and a bad car; only the seller knows. In Greshams law, however, presumably both buyer and seller can tell the difference between good and bad money. So the analogy is instructive, but not complete . B. Asymmetri

17、cal Information It has been seen that the good cars may be driven out of the market by the lemons. But in a more continuous case with different grades of goods, even worse pathologies can exist. For it is quite possible to have the bad driving out the not-so-bad driving out the medium driving out th

18、e not-so-good driving out the good in such a sequence of events that no market exists at all. One can assume that the demand for used automobiles depends most strongly upon two variables the price of the automobile p and the average quality of used cars traded, a, or Q = D (p, A). Both the supply of

19、 used cars and also the average quality p will depend upon the price, or p=j (p) and S=S(p). And in equilibrium the supply must equal the demand for the given average quality, or S(p) = D (p, p (p). As the price falls, normally the quality will also fall. And it is quite possible that no goods will

20、be traded at any price level. Such an example can be derived from utility theory. Assume that there are just two groups of traders: groups one and two. Give group one a utility function n U1 = M+ Xi i=1 where M is the consumption of goods other than automobiles, X1 is the quality of the I.T.H automo

21、bile, and N is the number of automobiles. Similarly, let n U2 = M+ X3/2Xi i=1 where M, X1, and N are defined as before. Three comments should be made about these utility functions: (1) without linear utility (say with logarithmic utility) one gets needlessly mired in algebraic complication. (2) The

22、use of linear utility allows a focus on the effects of asymmetry of information; with a concave utility function we would have to deal jointly with the usual risk variance effects of uncertainty and the special effects we wish to discuss here. (3) U1 and U2 have the odd characteristic that the addit

23、ion of a second car, or indeed a KTH car, adds the same amount of utility as the first. Again realism is sacrificed to avoid a diversion from the proper focus. To continue, it is assumed (1) that both type one traders and type two traders are Von Neumann Morgenstern maximizers of expected utility; (

24、2) that group one has N cars with uniformly distributed quality x, 0l D1=O / p p D2 =0 3/2 3/2. However, with price p, average quality is p/2 and therefore at no price will any trade take place at all: in spite of the fact that at any given price between 0 and 3 there are traders of type one who are

25、 willing to sell their automobiles at a price which traders of type two are willing to pay. C. Symmetric Information The foregoing is contrasted with the case of symmetric information. Suppose that the quality of all cars is uniformly distributed, O1 S(p)=O p 3/2. In equilibrium p=1 if Y2 Y2, in whi

26、ch case the income of type two traders is insufficient to buy all N automobiles, there is a gain in utility of Y2/2 units. Finally, it should be mentioned that in this example, if traders of groups one and two have the same probabilistic estimates about the quality of individual automobiles though t

27、hese estimates may vary from automobile to automobile(3), (4), and (5) will still describe equilibrium with one slight change: p will then represent the expected price of one quality unit. III. EXAMPLES AND APPLICATIONS A.Insurance It is a well-known fact that people over 65 have great difficulty in

28、 buying medical insurance. The natural question arises: why doesnt the price rise to match the risk? Our answer is that as the price level rises the people who insure themselves will be those who are increasingly certain that they will need the insurance; for error in medical check-ups, doctors symp

29、athy with older patients, and so on make it much easier for the applicant to assess the risks involved than the insurance company. The result is that the average medical condition of insurance applicants deteriorates as the price level rises with the result that no insurance sales may take place at

30、any price. This is strictly analogous to our automobiles case, where the average quality of used cars supplied fell with a corresponding fall in the price level. This agrees with the explanation in insurance textbooks: Generally speaking policies are not available at ages materially greater than six

31、ty-five. The term premiums are too high for any but the most pessimistic (which is to say the least healthy) insureds to find attractive. Thus there is a severe problem of adverse selection at these ages. The statistics do not contradict this conclusion. While demands for health insurance rise with

32、age, a 1956 national sample survey of 2,809 families with 8,898 persons shows that hospital insurance coverage drops from 63 per cent of those aged 45 to 54, to 31 per cent for those over 65. And surprisingly, this survey also finds average medical expenses for males aged 55 to 64 of $88, while male

33、s over 65 pay an average of $77.3 While non insured expenditure rises from $66 to $80 in these age groups, insured expenditure declines from $105 to $70. The conclusion is tempting that insurance companies are particularly wary of giving medical insurance to older people. The principle of “adverse s

34、election“ is potentially present in all lines of insurance. The following statement appears in an insurance textbook written at the Whats School: There is potential adverse selection in the fact that healthy term insurance policy holders may decide to terminate their coverage when they become older

35、and premiums mount. This action could leave an insurer with an undue proportion of below average risks and claims might be higher than anticipated. Adverse selection “appears (or at least is possible) whenever the individual or group insured has freedom to buy or not to buy, to choose the amount or

36、plan of insurance, and to persist or to discontinue as a policy holder.“ Group insurance, which is the most common form of medical insurance in the United States, picks out the healthy, for generally adequate health is a precondition for employment. At the same time this means that medical insurance

37、 is least available to those who need it most, for the insurance companies do their own “adverse selection.“ This adds one major argument in favor of medicare. On a cost benefit basis medicare may pay off: for it is quite possible that every individual in the market would be willing to pay the expec

38、ted cost of his medicare and buy insurance, yet no insurance company can afford to sell him a policy for at any price it will attract too many “lemons.“ The welfare economics of medicare, in this view, is exactly analogous to the usual classroom argument for public expenditure on roads. B. The Emplo

39、yment of Minorities The Lemons Principle also casts light on the employment of minorities. Employers may refuse to hire members of minority groups for certain types of jobs. This decision may not reflect irrationality or prejudice but profit maximization. For race may serve as a good statistic for t

40、he applicants social background, quality of schooling, and general job capabilities. Good quality schooling could serve as a substitute for this statistic; by grading students the schooling system can give a better indicator of quality than other more superficial characteristics. As T. W. Schultz wr

41、ites, “The educational establishment discovers and cultivates potential talent. The capabilities of children and mature students can never be known until found and cultivated.“ An untrained worker may have valuable natural talents, but these talents must be certified by “the educational establishmen

42、t“ before a company can afford to use them. The certifying establishment, however, must be credible; the unreliability of slum schools decreases the economic possibilities of their students. This lack may be particularly disadvantageous to members of already disadvantaged minority groups. For an emp

43、loyer may make a rational decision not to hire any members of these groups in responsible positions because it is difficult to distinguish those with good job qualifications from those with bad qualifications. This type of decision is clearly what George Stigler had in mind when he wrote, “in a regi

44、me of ignorance Enrico Fermi would have been a gardener, Von Neumann a checkout clerk at a drugstore.“ As a result, however, the rewards for work in slum schools tend to accrue to the group as a whole in raising its average quality rather than to the individual. Only insofar as information in additi

45、on to race is used is there any incentive for training. An additional worry is that the Office of Economic Opportunity is going to use cost-benefit analysis to evaluate its programs. For many benefits may be external. The benefit from training minority groups may arise as much from raising the avera

46、ge quality of the group as from raising the quality of the individual trainee; and, likewise, the returns may be distributed over the whole group rather than to the individual. C. The Costs of Dishonesty The Lemons model can be used to make some comments on the costs of dishonesty. Consider a market

47、 in which goods are sold honestly or dishonestly; quality may be represented, or it may be misrepresented. The purchasers problem, of course, is to identify quality. The presence of people in the market who are willing to offer inferior goods tends to drive the market out of existence as in the case

48、 of our automobile “lemons.“ It is this possibility that represents the major costs of dishonesty for dishonest dealings tend to drive honest dealings out of the market. There may be potential buyers of good quality products and there may be potential sellers of such products in the appropriate pric

49、e range; however, the presence of people who wish to pawn bad wares as good wares tends to drive out the legitimate business. The cost of dishonesty, therefore, lies not only in the amount by which the purchaser is cheated; the cost also must include the loss incurred from driving legitimate business out of existence. Dishonesty in business is a serious problem in underdeveloped countries. Our model gives a possible structure to this statement and delineates the nature of the

展开阅读全文
相关资源
相关搜索

当前位置:首页 > 学术论文资料库 > 外文翻译

Copyright © 2018-2021 Wenke99.com All rights reserved

工信部备案号浙ICP备20026746号-2  

公安局备案号:浙公网安备33038302330469号

本站为C2C交文档易平台,即用户上传的文档直接卖给下载用户,本站只是网络服务中间平台,所有原创文档下载所得归上传人所有,若您发现上传作品侵犯了您的权利,请立刻联系网站客服并提供证据,平台将在3个工作日内予以改正。